Foreign Exchange Rates
Most common contact with foreign exchange occurs when we travel or buy things in
other countries. Suppose a U.S. tourist travelling in London wants to buy a sweater.
Price tag is 100 pounds (Symbol for pounds: £).
Current exchange rate
|
Price of sweater in dollars
|
$1.45 to £1
|
100 x 1.45 = $145.00
|
$1.30 to £1
|
100 x 1.30 = $130.00
|
$1.60 to £1
|
100 x 1.60 = $160.00
|
$2.00 to £1
|
100 x 2.00 = $200.00
|
For businesses or governments that trade billions of dollars, even small changes
in the exchange rate become significant.
When the United States dollar (symbol: USD) becomes stronger, then foreign goods
and services become cheaper, and goods and services from the United States will
become more expensive. Consequently, imports to the United States will increase
and exports will decrease.
When the dollar becomes weaker with respect to other currencies, then the opposite
happens: goods and services from the United States become cheaper, thereby increasing
exports, and foreign goods and services will become more expensive, thereby lessening
imports.
Thus, the trade balance of any country is largely determined by the value
of the domestic currency in relation to other currencies.
It would seem logical that if the dollar, for instance, weakens, the U.S. trade
balance will improve, as exports would rise and imports would decrease. However,
the U.S. trade balance usually worsens for a few months.
Most import/export orders are taken months in advance. Immediately after a currency’s
value drops, the volume of imports remains about the same, but the prices in terms
of the home currency rise. On the other hand, the value of the domestic exports
remains the same, and the difference in values worsens the trade balance until the
imports and exports adjust to the new exchange rates. This can be represented graphically
by the J-Curve:
The J-Curve depicts the lag between the currency depreciation
of a country and the improvement in its trade balance.
|
|
Source: New York Federal Reserve Bank.
|
Exchange rates are an important consideration when making international investment
decisions. The money invested overseas incurs an exchange rate risk.
When an investor decides to cash out, or bring his money home, any gains could be
magnified or wiped out depending on the change in the exchange rates in the interim.
Thus, changes in exchange rates can have many repercussions on an economy:
- Affects the prices of imported goods.
- Affects the overall level of price
and wage inflation.
- Influences tourism patterns.
- Will influence consumers’
buying decisions and investors’ long-term commitments.
Determination of Foreign Exchange Rates
Exchange rates respond directly to all sorts of events, both tangible and psychological:
- Business cycles;
- Balance of payments;
- Political developments;
- New tax laws;
- Stock market news;
- Inflationary expectations;
- Interest rate differentials;
- International
investment patterns;
- And government and central bank monetary policies among others.
At the heart of this complex market are the same forces of demand and supply that
determine the prices of goods and services in any free market. If at any given rate,
the demand for a currency is greater than its supply, its price will rise. If supply
exceeds demand, the price will fall.
The supply of a nation’s currency is influenced by that nation’s monetary authority,
which is usually its central bank. Government and central banks closely monitor
economic activity to keep money supply at a level appropriate to achieve their economic
goals. Too much money increases inflation, causing the value of the currency to
decline and prices to rise; whereas too little money can slow economic growth and
possibly cause rising unemployment.
Monetary authorities must decide whether economic conditions call for a larger or
smaller increase in the money supply.
Sources for currency demand on the FX market
The currency of a growing economy with relative price stability and a wide variety
of competitive goods and services will be more in demand than that of a country
in political turmoil, with high inflation and few marketable exports. Money will
flow to wherever it can get the highest return with the least risk. If a nation’s
financial instruments, such as stocks and bonds, offer relatively high rates of
return at relatively low risk, foreigners will demand its currency to invest in
them. FX traders speculate about how different events will move the exchange rates.
For example:
- News of political instability in other countries drives up demand for U.S. dollars
as investors are looking for a safe haven for their money.
- A country’s interest rates rise and its currency appreciates as foreign investors
seek higher returns than they can get in their own countries.
- Developing nations undertaking successful economic reforms may experience currency
appreciation as foreign investors seek new opportunities.
Theoretical Currency Exchange Rates
There are some who believe that some currency exchange rates are not what they should
be. For instance, there is a bill in Congress to correct any fundamental exchange
rate misalignment, a bill which is actually aimed at China because Congress
believes that the Chinese yuan is seriously undervalued against the United States
dollar. But how does one ascertain the misalignment of currency rates? Is there
a true exchange rate and can it be determined?
There are at least 3 methods that purport to reveal the true exchange rate, or to
at least reveal misalignments.
One common method is purchasing power parity (PPP), which is
the common assumption that the amount of currency needed to purchase a specified
basket of goods should be equal to any other currency needed to buy that same basket
of goods. However, this measure disregards the effects of comparative advantage,
which is the advantage that some countries have over others in producing a particular
product because of location or other factors. Moreover, purchasing power parity
is difficult to measure, although the Economist magazine publishes a
Big Mac Index, which is the price, in local currencies, to buy a Big Mac
hamburger at the many McDonald's restaurants located throughout the world, and compares
this to the United States dollar (USD). The Big Mac Index shows what the implied
PPP is in USD, which is equal to the price in local currency divided by the price
in the United States, and compares this to what the actual exchange rate is. None
of the exchange rates shown in the
latest index shows purchasing power parity, although some come close, which
could simply be a coincidence. Nonetheless, there are more sophisticated models
that purport to give a truer picture of PPP by accounting for differences in productivity
or income.
However, purchasing power parity does not account for international capital flow,
which is far more important in determining exchange rates. For instance, countries
with investments that yield the highest return will have large inflows of foreign
capital, which will certainly have an impact on exchange rates, but capital flows
are not related to PPP.
Another method to calculate what the exchange rate should be is the fundamental equilibrium
exchange rate (FEER), which is based on a sustainable current-account
balance and internal balance, with low inflation and full employment. A sustainable
current-account balance is predicated on the simple fact that a country
cannot continue accumulating more and more of a single currency unless it is actively
intervening to keep the exchange rate low. Thus, China's continually growing current-account
surplus of United States dollars is given as evidence that the yuan is seriously
undervalued. However, a large current-account surplus may result because the people
of a country invest more in foreign countries, or because the country has a low
interest rate. A good example of why the current-account balance could be misleading
is to examine why the Japanese yen is low compared to other currencies. The current
interest rate in Japan is about 0.5%, the lowest of the developed countries. Because
the interest rate is so low, and much higher elsewhere, many Japanese investors
invest their money outside of their country, but to do so, they must exchange Japanese
yen for other currencies. Another factor is the carry trade, where investors all
over the world borrow yen at the low interest rate, and convert it into currencies
where interest rates are higher, such as in New Zealand, which currently has an
interest rate of 8%.
Then there is the behavioral equilibrium exchange rate, which is predicated
on the invariance of cause and effect, so what economic variables influenced currency
exchange rates in the past, such as productivity growth or net foreign assets, will
also influence future currency exchange rates. While this seems plausible, how does
one determine that a particular set of variables and their relative importance determined
the exchange rate in the past? Will the importance of each economic variable change
when other variables change, and if so, how?
The Actual Determination, or Microeconomics, of Foreign Exchange Rates
- Microeconomics
- The study of a single economic unit, which may be a firm,
a household, or an organization. The interaction of all of these units is the purview
of macroeconomics.
- Rollover
- Swapping 1 forex contract for another with
a later delivery date, which is usually done because the trader who agreed to the
contract, does not actually want the delivery of the currency, but simply wants
to trade for profit.
While there are many theories about what actually sets the foreign exchange rate,
there is a simple way to visualize the true determiner of rates. Keep in mind that
banks do most of the actual trading and all of it is done in the over-the-counter
market, where 1 bank communicates with other traders, mostly banks to satisfy its
currency needs. You may be a forex trader trading with a broker, but that broker
trades with banks. Also, most forex trading done by retail traders does not actually
involve the transference of currency. The currency contracts are simply rolled over
into new contracts before actual delivery takes place. However, if you were a businessperson
or a government with a real need to trade actual currency, you would go to a bank
to satisfy your needs, because that's what banks do.
Now imagine that you owned an international bank in Switzerland. The main currency
of Switzerland is the Swiss franc (CHF), but since you are an international bank,
you must deal in other currencies as well. Let's take the United States dollar as
an example. Some of your customers will want to exchange francs for dollars, and
some will want dollars for francs. But how many dollars do you want to keep? You
want enough to satisfy your customers' need for dollars plus some reserves for unknown
immediate future demands.
Now, because an international bank actually needs different currencies to do business,
it will keep some of the dollars that it gets from customers so that it can give
other customers the dollars that they demand. But what happens when the bank starts
getting too many dollars in relation to that bank's customers' demand for dollars.
The simple solution is to simply reduce the price of the dollar in terms of Swiss
francs. When a customer comes in to exchange dollars for francs, you start giving
fewer francs per dollar. This immediately lowers the number of francs that your
bank pays for each dollar. Ergo, this lowers the exchange rate of dollars for francs.
But suppose you continue to get more dollars than you can use in your local business—maybe
because some local exporter has a hot new product that's selling wildly in the United
States, so the exporter has no choice but to trade dollars for francs, because he
has to pay his workers and suppliers in Swiss francs, since the business is in Switzerland.
As an international banker, you know that there are other banks that will have a
need for dollars, and so you call them, or communicate with them over an electronic
network, such as the Internet, and trade dollars for Swiss francs. You call another
bank in another town that happens to have a United States international firm doing
business in the town. While the business pays its local workers in francs and receives
revenues in francs, it needs to send dollars back home in the United States, so
it goes to the local bank to exchange francs for dollars. Because the bank doesn't
have enough dollars on hand to satisfy the U.S. business, that bank readily agrees
to exchange dollars for francs with your bank. You can also contact banks in New
York, some of which, will have a need for more francs than dollars.
But you also know that the Swiss government wants to keep the exchange rate of francs
for dollars low, so that exports to the United States increase and imports decrease,
so you contact the central bank of Switzerland, the Swiss National Bank.
To carry out the government's policy of lowering the exchange rate of the franc
against the dollar, the central bank agrees to buy your dollars for francs. If there
is no other need for the dollars, the central bank simply holds them in reserve
to satisfy the Swiss government's desire to lower the exchange rate of francs for
dollars.
Thus, the exchange rate that your bank sets will be determined by the total demand
from your customers and from other banks. But note that this exchange rate will
tend to be equal to the rate set by other banks. Why is this necessarily so? Remember,
the exchange rate that you set ultimately depends on demand on both your customers
and other banks that your bank trades with. If you are offering fewer dollars per
franc than other banks because of the excess of supply over demand from your customers,
then those banks will buy dollars from your bank until your rates become equal.
So this is how demand and supply actually work in the microeconomic view.
The demand and supply of currency ultimately originates with the people; even when
governments set monetary policy through their central banks, it is to satisfy the
needs of their residents; banks simply equalize this supply and demand all over
the world by trading with each other.
In the end, it could be concluded that the true currency exchange rate is what it
actually is.